Los orígenes de la mentalidad capitalista y los agentes económicos activos: una hipótesis global

Autores/as

  • Carlos Newland ESEADE

Palabras clave:

capitalismo, mercado, historia, economía

Resumen

La Anglosfera, el norte de Europa y la Sinósfera son conglomerados de países que incluyen poblaciones con mentalidades afines a la economía de mercado. Estos países tienden a tener instituciones conducentes a la eficiencia económica.  Este trabajo, basado en una intuición de F. Hayek, presenta la hipótesis de que la mentalidad capitalista se origina, en buena medida, en las estructuras agrarias del pasado, más concretamente en la proporción de la población acostumbrada a interactuar en el mercado sin grandes restricciones. Esta situación generó una comprensión y aceptación del funcionamiento y virtudes de las economías competitivas. En el resto del mundo, por contraste, una gran parte de la población rural estaba limitada por restricciones feudales o sufrían de interferencias comunales, gubernamentales o tribales. Otra parte se desempeñaba pasivamente en una situación de esclavitud o como trabajadores en haciendas. Esta situación generó una cierta pasividad que se trasladó a una mentalidad más propensa a aceptar la intervención gubernamental.

Descargas

Los datos de descargas todavía no están disponibles.

Citas

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. & Robinson, J. A. (2001). “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation”. The American Economic Review, 91 (5), 1369-1401.

Allen, R. (1999). Slaves, Freedmen and Indentured Laborers in Colonial Mauritius. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Allen, R. (2009). “Agricultural Productivity and Rural Incomes in England and the Yangtze Delta, c. 1620-c. 1820”. The Economic History Review, 62 (3), 525-550.

Aoki, M. (2013). “Historical Sources of Institutional Trajectories in Economic Development: China, Japan and Korea Compared”. Socio-Economic Review, 11 (2/1), 233–263.

Arcondo, A. (ed.) (1995). La población de Córdoba en 1813. Córdoba: Facultad de Ciencias Económicas. Instituto de Economía y Finanzas.

Bauer, A. J. (1971). “Chilean Rural Labor in the Nineteenth Century”. The American Historical Review, 76 (4): 1059-108.

Berger, P. L. & Luckmann, T. (1966). The Social Construction of Reality: A Treatise in the Sociology of Knowledge. Garden City: Anchor Books.

Berman, B. (1998). “Ethnicity, patronage and the African State: The politics of uncivil nationalism”. African Affairs, 97 (388), 305-334.

Berdiaev, N. (1915). The Psychology of the Russian People. The Soul of Russia. http://www.berdyaev.com/berdiaev/berd_lib/1915_007.html

Bergad, L. W. (2007). The Comparative Histories of Slavery in Brazil, Cuba, and the United States. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Béteille, A. (1980). “The Indian Village: Past and Present”. In Hobsbawm, E. J., Kula, W. Ashok Mitra, K. N. & Sachs, R. (eds.). Peasants in History. Essays in Honour of Daniel Thorner. Calcutta: Oxford University Press.

Bonacci, G. & Meckel, A. (2017). “Revisiting Slavery and the Slave Trade in Ethiopia”. Northeast African Studies, 5-30.

Booth, A. (1998). The Indonesian Economy in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries: A History of Missed Opportunities. Basingstoke: Macmillan and New York: St. Martin’s Press.

Bosma, U. (2011). Labour Relations in Java 1650, 1800, 1900. https://datasets.socialhistory.org/dataset.xhtml?persistentId=hdl:10622/LCALNW

Botelho, T. (2016). Brazil 1650,1800 [Global Collaboratory on the History of Labour Relations 1500-2000 Dataset], http://hdl.handle.net/10622/JLFQZP

Cardoso, C. (1988). “The Peasant Breach in the Slave System: New Developments in Brazil”. Luso-Brazilian Review. 25 (1), 49-57.

Comadrán Ruiz, J. (1971). Algunos aspectos de la estructura demográfica y socio-económica de Mendoza hacia 1822-1824. Primer Congreso de Historia Argentina y Regional: celebrado en San Miguel de Tucumán, del 14 al 16 de agosto de 1971. Buenos Aires: 405-423.

Czegledi, P. & Newland, C. (2018a). “How is the Pro-capitalist Mentality Globally Distributed?”. Economic Affairs, 38 (2), 240-256.

Czegledi, P. & Newland, C. (2018b). “Measuring Global Free Market Ideology 1990-2015”. In Gwartney, J., Lawson, R., Hall, J. & Murphy, R. (eds.) Economic Freedom of the World: 2018 Annual Report. Fraser Institute. <https://www.fraserinstitute.org/studies/economic-freedom>: 189 –211.

Denzau, A. & North, D. (1994). “Shared mental models: ideologies and institutions”. Kyklos, 47, 3-30.

De Vries, J & van der Woude, A. M. (1997). The First Modern Economy. Success, Failure, and Perseverance of the Dutch Economy from 1500 to 1815. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Dimitrova-Grajzl, V. (2007). “The Great Divide Revisited: Ottoman and Habsburg Legacies on Transition”. Kyklos, 60(4), 539-558.

Doucouliagos, C. & Ulubasoglu, M. A. (2006). “Economic Freedom and Economic Growth: Does Specification Make a Difference?”. European Journal of Political Economy, 22, 60–81.

Engerman, S. L. & Sokoloff, K. L. (2002). “Factor Endowments, Inequality, and Paths of Development among New World Economies”. Economia, 3, 41-102.

European Values Study (EVS) (2015). European Values Study Longitudinal Data File 1981 2008. ZA4804. Data File Version 3.0.0, Cologne: GESIS Data Archive. doi:10.4232/1.12253.

Feldmann, H. (2018). “Do Linguistic Structures Affect Human Capital? The Case of Pronoun Drop”. Kyklos, 72(1), 29-54.

Fenske, J. (2000). Does land abundance explain African Institutions? https://economics.wustl.edu/files/economics/imce/fenskelandabundance.pdf

Fukazawa, H. (2008). “Agrarian Relations and Land Revenu. The Medieval Deccan and Maharashtra”. In Kumar, D. & Raychaudhur, T. The Cambridge Economic History of India (Vol I c. 1200 - c. 1750). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Gerschenkron, A. (1962). Backwardness in Historical Perspective, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Gilbar, G. G. (1979). “The Persian Economy in the Mid-19th Century”. Die Welt des Islams, 19, 177-211.

Góngora, M. (1960). Origen de los inquilinos de Chile Central. Santiago de Chile: Universidad de Chile.

Gorshkov, B. B. (2018). Peasants in Russia from Serfdom to Stalin. Accommodation, Survival, Resistance. London: Bloomsbury Academic.

Grupo de Investigación en Historia Rural Rioplatense (2004). “La sociedad rural bonaerense a principios del siglo XIX. Un análisis a partir de las categorías ocupacionales”. In Fradkin, R. & Garavaglia, J. C. En busca de un tiempo perdido: la economía de Buenos Aires en el país de la abundancia, 1750-1865. Buenos Aires: Prometeo.

Habib, I. (2008). “Agrarian Relations and Land Revenu. North India”. In Kumar, D. & Raychaudhur, T. The Cambridge Economic History of India (Vol I c. 1200 - c. 1750). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Habtamu Mengistie, T. (2011). Land tenure and agrarian social structure in Ethiopia, 1636-1900. Ph. D. Thesis Dissertation University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign.

Hayami, A. (2015). Japan’s Industrious Revolution Economic and Social Transformations in the Early Modern Period. Tokio: Springer.

Hudson Banks, K. & Stephens, J. (2018). “Reframing Internalized Racial Oppression and Charting a way Forward”. Social Issues and Policy Review, 12 (1), 91-111.

Hayek, F. (1960). The Constitution of Liberty. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

Hayek, F. (1976). Law, Legislation and Liberty (Volume 2: The Mirage of Social Justice). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

Jones, E. L. (1988). Crecimiento recurrente. El cambio económico en la historia mundial. Madrid: Alianza.

Khitrov, D. (2016). “Tributary Labor in the Russian Empire in the Eighteenth Century: Factors in Development”. IRSH, 61, 49–70.

Kula, W. (1980). “Money and serfs in eighteenth century Poland”. In Hobsbawm, E. J., Kula, W., Ashok Mitra, K. N. & Sachs, R. (eds.) Peasants in History. Essays in Honour of Daniel Thorner. Calcutta: Oxford University Press.

Kulikoff, A. (1992). The Agrarian Origins of American Capitalism. Charlottesville: University Press of Virginia.

Kumar, D. & Raychaudhuri, T. (eds.) (2008). The Cambridge Economic History of India (Vol I c. 1200 - c. 1750). Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

Lana-Berasain, J. M. (2016). Spain 1800,1900,2000 [Global Collaboratory on the History of Labour Relations 1500-2000 Dataset]. http://hdl.handle.net/10622/CH6ZP5

Lindert, P. & Williamson, J. (1982). “Revising England’s Social Tables 1688–1812”. Explorations in Economic History, 19 (4), 385-408.

Lovejoy, P. (2012). Transformations in slavery: a history of slavery in Africa. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Lundh, C. (2005). “Criados agrícolas en la Suecia del XIX. El caso de Escania”. Historia Agraria, 35, 93-114.

Lyashchenko, P. (1949). History of The National Economy of Russia. New York: Macmillan.

Maeder, E. (1964). “La estructura demográfica y ocupacional de Corrientes y Entre Ríos en 1820”. Trabajos y Comunicaciones, 12, 111-138.

Malefakis, E. (1970). Agrarian Reform and Peasant Revolution in Spain: Origins of the Civil War. New Haven: Yale University Press.

McCloskey, D. N. (2016). Bourgeois Equality: How Ideas, Not Capital or Institutions, Enriched the Modern World. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Moll-Murata, C. (2011). Methodological Paper Japan 1800. file:///home/chronos/u-f573f4cc3130153a6a84f725f635ebe69aa4bea1/Downloads/Nueva%20carpeta/Japan_1800_Methodological_Paper.pdf

Morrison, C. & Snyder, W. (2000). “The Income Inequality of France in Historical Perspective”. European Review of Economic History, 4, 59-83.

Mupfuvi, B. (2014). Land to the people: Peasants and nationalism in the development of land ownership structure in Zimbabwe from pre-colonialism to the Unilateral Declaration of Independence (UDI) period. Unpub. Doctoral. Diss. University of Salford.

Newland, C. (2018). “Is Support for Capitalism Declining in the World? A Free-Market Mentality Index (FMMI) 1990–2012”. Independent Review, 22 (4): 569-583.

North, D. (2005). Understanding the Process of Economic Change. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

North, M. (2014). “Serfdom and Corvée Labour in the Baltic Area 16th-18th Centuries”. In Cavaciocchi, S. (ed.) Chiavitù e servaggionell’economia europea. Secc. XI-XVIII: Serfdom and Slavery in the European Economy. 11 Th - 18 Th. Centuries. Florence: Florence University Press.

Ogilvie, S. & Carus, A. W. (2014). “Institutions and Economic Growth in Historical Perspective”. In Aghion, P. and Durlauf, S. N. (eds.). Handbook of Economic Growth (Volume 2). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

Ouweneel, A. & Hoekstra, R. (1998). Las tierras de los pueblos de indios en el altiplano de México, 1560-1920. Una aportación teórica interpretativa.

http://www.cedla.uva.nl/50_publications/pdf/cuadernos/cuad01.pdf

Overton, M. (1996). Agricultural Revolution in England: The Transformation of the Agrarian Economy 1500- 1850. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Patterson, O. (1982). Slavery and Social Death: A Comparative Study. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Pomeranz, K. (2000). The Great Divergence. China, Europe and the Making of the Modern World Economy. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

Pomeranz, K. (2011). Development with Chinese Characteristics? Convergence and Divergence in Long Run and Comparative Perspective. European University Institute. Max Weber Program.

Porter, M. (2000). “Attitudes, Values, Beliefs and the Microeconomics of Prosperity”. In Harrison, L. E. & Huntington, S. P. (eds.). Culture Matters: How Values Shape Human Progress. New York: Basic Books.

Rancour-Laferriere, D. (1995). The Slave Soul of Russia: Moral Masochism and the Cult of Suffering. New York: New York University Press.

Regnier, D. A. P. (2012). Why not marry them? History, essentialism and the condition of slave descendants among the southern Betsileo (Madagascar). Unpub. Doctoral. Diss. The London School of Economics and Political Science.

Remani, K. (2015). “Agrestic Slaves in Cochin State: Perspectives from Pulaya Untouchables in Pre- Colonial and British Rule”. IOSR Journal of Humanities and Social Science (IOSR-JHSS), 20 (5), 54-57.

Richards, A. (1982). Egypt’s Agricultural Development, 1800–1980. Technical and Social Change. Colorado: Westview Press.

Robb, P. (1992). “Peasants' choices? Indian agriculture and the limits of commercialization in nineteenth century Bihai”. Economic History Review, XLV, 1, 97-119.

Secretaría de Programación y Presupuesto. (1977). Primer Censo de Población de la Nueva España, 1790. México.

Sée, H. (2004). Economic and Social Conditions in France during the Eighteenth Century. Kitchene: Batoche Books.

Slicher van Bath, H. (1963). The Agrarian History of Western Europe, A. D. 500–1850. New York: St. Martin’s Press.

Solana Ruiz, J. (2000). “Las clases sociales en Andalucía. Un recorrido sociohistórico”. Gazeta de Antropología 16, artículo 08. http://hdl.handle.net/10481/750.

Sugihara, K. (2004). “The State and the Industrious Revolution in Tokugawa Japan”. Working Papers of the Global Economic History Network (GEHN), 02-04, Department of Economic History, London School of Economics.

Tilly, C. (1983). Demographic Origins of the European Proletariat. University of Michigan.

Turner Main, J. (2015). Social Structure of Revolutionary America. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

Vanhaute, E. (2001). “Rich Agriculture and Poor Farmers: Land, Landlords and Farmers in Flanders in the Eighteenth and Nineteenth Centuries”. Rural History, 12 (1), 19-40.

Warriner, D., Cushing, G. F., Tappe, E. D., de S. Pinto, V. & Auty, P. (1965). Contrasts in Emerging Societies: Readings in the Social and Economic History of South-Eastern Europe in the Nineteenth Century. London: The Athlone Press.

Weber, M. (1904–05). The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. London: Routledge (2001).

World Values Survey (WVS) (2015). World Values Survey 1981–2014 official aggregate v. 20150418. Aggregate File Producer: JDSystems, Madrid.

Descargas

Publicado

27-12-2019

Cómo citar

Newland, C. (2019). Los orígenes de la mentalidad capitalista y los agentes económicos activos: una hipótesis global. Cultura Económica, 37(98), 11–30. Recuperado a partir de http://200.16.86.39/index.php/CECON/article/view/2728